Dalit Politics in India Recognition without Redistribution
-Radha Sarkar,
Amar Sarkar
(Economic & Political Weekly
EPW may 14, 2016 vol. lI No 20 15)
Dalit political parties in North
and Central India have overwhelmingly pursued an agenda of recognition, calling
for equal respect, rather than one of redistribution. While this has improved
the social and economic standing of Dalits better situated in terms of class,
it has failed to substantively improve the lives of the majority of Dalits.
Ultimately, Dalits’ quest for equal treatment will be limited so long as it
lacks a redistributive politics that addresses exploitative economic relations.
How should we understand the rise
of caste-based politics among India’s Dalits since the 1990s? Should we
celebrate it as the empowerment of a historically oppressed community and a
major success of Indian democracy, as some scholars have (Jaffrelot 2003; Kohli
2001; Varshney 2000)? Or should we be more sceptical in examining the gains and
limitations? We argue that caste-based politics cannot achieve social justice
for Dalits unless it takes class into account, which it has largely failed to.
The politics of recognition employed by Dalit parties has brought only limited
gains for Dalits on the whole as the benefits associated with it have been
reaped by Dalits better situated in terms of class. Ultimately, Dalits’ quest
for equal treatment will be limited so long as it lacks a redistributive
politics to address exploitative economic relations. We use the case of the
Bahujan Samaj Party (BSP) in the northern state of Uttar Pradesh (UP)—one of
the largest and most electorally successful of caste based parties—and its project
for Dalit equality to illustrate our arguments.
Social Justice
Nancy Fraser
(1998) distinguishes two conceptions of social justice: one that centres on
redistributive claims, comprising calls for a more equitable distribution of
goods and resources; and a second conception built on claims for recognition
with the goal of a “difference friendly world” that accords equal respect to a
plurality of social groups (Fraser 1998: 1). While redistribution has had a
central place in calls for justice, Fraser highlights the equal importance of
recognition in achieving justice for those groups for whom “institutionalized
patterns of interpretation and valuation [have] impede[d] the parity of
participation in social life” (Fraser 1998: 4). Fraser argues that to adequately
add ress injustice, the politics of redistribution and recognition must be
employed tog ether: either one on its own is incapable of dealing with the
complex cultural and economic realities of injustice. Her argument primarily
concerns women but is also well suited to explain the nature of caste
oppression in India. Caste, like gender in Fraser’s account, is a two-sided
category, composed of economic and cul tural dimensions. And as with gender,
redressing caste-based injustice calls for attention to both redistribution and
recognition (Fraser 1998: 2)
.
.
Recognition vs Redistribution
They are concerned primarily with
changes to the cultural order as means of securing equal treatment in
social relations, or, in Fraser’s words,
they pursue “parity of participation in social life” (1998: 4). But changes to
the cultural order can at best address misrecognition, or the unfairly low
social status accorded to a group; they are unable to address what Fraser terms
maldistribution, or the unjust distribution of resources and goods. If caste
constituted the sole principle of distribution, then it would correspond
perfectly with class. If all members of a caste engaged in their traditional
occupations, then we could expect few differences between property ownership,
education, wealth or income between the members of any one caste or sub-caste
(Weiner 2001). Misrecognition of a group’s status in society would directly
entail maldistribution, and a politics of recognition would serve to address
injustices of distribution as well as recognition. However, the reality of
caste is more complex, for caste and class do not map seamlessly onto one
another. With changes in economy and policy, caste Hindus as well as Dalits
have become increasingly differentiated internally. With deregulation,
liberalisation of the economy and higher economic growth rates, individuals
from various rungs of the caste hierarchy have gained diverse economic benefits
(Weiner 2001; Kohli 2001). As some members of lower castes acquire higher levels
of education and have benefitted from caste-based reservations in government employment,
class divisions among them have increased. Weiner (2001) predicts an increasing
trend of social mobility for educated, urban Dalits; the prospects for the more
numerous rural sections of the Dalit population, with less education, are less
optimistic. Thus, all the members of any one caste do not belong to the same
class: caste and class are not interchangeable, and we cannot infer one
directly from the other. Consequently, a politics of recognition does not, in
and of itself, entail a politics of redistribution. In the remainder of this
article, we demonstrate the ways in which the caste based politics of Dalit
parties are unable to address the economic dimensions of oppression, in
addition the cultural ones, for the overwhelming majority of Dalits.
The Case of Uttar Pradesh
Consider, for instance, the
pro-Dalit BSP in UP. The BSP emerged as a competitor for state-level power in
1991, winning 9.4% of the vote that year. In 2007, it won a landslide victory
with 30.6% of the vote (Jeffrey et al 2008). The BSP’s attempts to better the
social, economic, and political position of Dalits in UP comprised of two
interlinked strategies. The first consisted in a symbolic transformation of the
landscape of UP—parks, statues, and libraries were dedicated to Dalit leaders;
and hospitals, stadia, and educational institutions were renamed along similar
lines (Jeffrey et al 2008). The BSP’s second strategy was to alter the
implementation of existing government policies rather than effect new
legislation (Chandra 2004). For example, the BSP sought to change the nature of
the state government by transferring Dalits into key positions in the
bureaucracy and by expanding Dalit presence in the police force. In the six
months that the BSP’s Mayawati was chief minister in 1997, she transferred
1,350 civil and police officers (Jaffrelot 2003: 419), made a concerted effort
to recruit Dalits to the police force, and made existing reserved seats in government training and
professional training more accessible to Dalits (Chandra 2004; Hasan 2001). In
sum, the strategy of the BSP was to raise the profile of UP’s Dalits writ large
by increasing their presence and power in the bureaucratic and coercive
apparatuses, as well as in the symbolic landscape. Clearly, the BSP improved the
political and economic standing of some Dalits. Varshney (2000) argues that,
although the BSP has not substantially improved the economic position of
ordinary Dalits, it has nonetheless benefitted the Dalit community, politically
and symbolically, across North India. He suggests that Dalits are better
positioned to challenge the legitimacy of caste discrimination and to engage in
politics. Jaffrelot (2003) goes further in suggesting that many ordinary Dalits
are using their recently acquired state-level representation to significantly
improve their access to political resources, economic goods, and social
contacts in rural UP. While the rise of low-caste politics has indeed altered local-level
politics to a certain extent (Jeffrey et al 2008), hailing the BSP as the
harbinger of a “silent revolution” (Jaffrelot 2003) is as yet premature, for a
politics of recognition, divorced from that of redistribution, is limited from
the very outset. Without a radical shift in the distribution of economic and
social opportunities, a politics of recognition does little to reconfigure
entrenched power relations.
Socio-economic Inequality
The
limits of a politics of recognition are evinced by the BSP. Even as it has embraced
a politics of recognition and advanced a largely symbolic agenda, the BSP has
failed to intervene in disputes over land and labour and to implement policies
that address inequality and poverty in
UP (Jeffrey et al 2008). The realities of socio-economic inequality, rooted in
unequal land and asset ownership, also impact the ways in which Dalits are able
(or unable) to take advantage of the policies of recognition offered to them.
While reservations in state educational institutions and government offices have
been implemented with the claim of advancing Dalits’ economic, political, and
social standing, in reality they have done little for the majority of the
community. For instance, rural Chamars, a Dalit group in UP, argue that
reservations have little impact on their community’s chances of securing
government work because the competition for reserved government posts is fierce and corrupt (Jeffrey et al 2008). The
Chamars’ less prestigious education, obtained primarily from rural state
schools with poor educational standards— the only schools most Chamar families
can afford—combined with a lack of money for bribes marginalised their bid for
government jobs relative to urban members of their caste (Jeffrey et al 2008).
The politics of recognition have thus allowed those Dalit individuals better positioned in the class hierarchy to take advantage of the opportunities offered for recognition. Furthermore, a politics of recognition without redistribution is limited even in its pursuit of respect in a largely rural society where dignity and respect are bound up with landownership and use. Landownership has been a source of self-respect and a claim to respectful treatment from others across the Indian countryside (Bhatia 2005). For the majority of rural Dalits, their landlessness has left them completely dependent on landlords. The skewed labour relations engendered by this pattern of land ownership has been a source of enduring humiliation among Dalits and has exposed them to continued exploitation by their employers (Bhatia 2005). Respect for Dalits can only be meaningfully secured through a direct intervention in the labour relations between them and other castes—either through land redistribution, heightened minimum wage regulation, or other redistributive measures. The aim of a politics of recognition— parity in participation in social life—can only be achieved with redistribution. All of this is not to deny the value of a politics of recognition. Dalits have been denied dignity and respect, even their humanity has too often been denied. These harms are indeed injustices of recognition and demand remedies of recognition of equal worth. However, a Dalit politics of recognition that is unable to substantiate a redistributive agenda is doomed to be shallow, bringing tangible gains to those better off in class terms while permitting at best symbolic achievements for many. Furthermore, such a politics ignores the interrelated nature of economic and social relations: without significant redistribution, Dalits are fated to continued dependence on higher castes to make ends meet. This economic dependence in turn fosters relations of exploitation that preclude the parity of participation in social life to which a politics of recognition aspires. Indian democracy can only be (at most) a partial success without the full social and economic incorporation of the country’s most oppressed and marginalised groups.
The politics of recognition have thus allowed those Dalit individuals better positioned in the class hierarchy to take advantage of the opportunities offered for recognition. Furthermore, a politics of recognition without redistribution is limited even in its pursuit of respect in a largely rural society where dignity and respect are bound up with landownership and use. Landownership has been a source of self-respect and a claim to respectful treatment from others across the Indian countryside (Bhatia 2005). For the majority of rural Dalits, their landlessness has left them completely dependent on landlords. The skewed labour relations engendered by this pattern of land ownership has been a source of enduring humiliation among Dalits and has exposed them to continued exploitation by their employers (Bhatia 2005). Respect for Dalits can only be meaningfully secured through a direct intervention in the labour relations between them and other castes—either through land redistribution, heightened minimum wage regulation, or other redistributive measures. The aim of a politics of recognition— parity in participation in social life—can only be achieved with redistribution. All of this is not to deny the value of a politics of recognition. Dalits have been denied dignity and respect, even their humanity has too often been denied. These harms are indeed injustices of recognition and demand remedies of recognition of equal worth. However, a Dalit politics of recognition that is unable to substantiate a redistributive agenda is doomed to be shallow, bringing tangible gains to those better off in class terms while permitting at best symbolic achievements for many. Furthermore, such a politics ignores the interrelated nature of economic and social relations: without significant redistribution, Dalits are fated to continued dependence on higher castes to make ends meet. This economic dependence in turn fosters relations of exploitation that preclude the parity of participation in social life to which a politics of recognition aspires. Indian democracy can only be (at most) a partial success without the full social and economic incorporation of the country’s most oppressed and marginalised groups.
References
Basu, Ipshita (2012): “The
Politics of Recognition and Redistribution: Development, Tribal Identity
Politics and Distributive Justice in India’s Jharkhand,” Development and
Change, Vol 43, No 6, pp 1291–1312. Bhatia,
Bela (2005): “The Naxalite Movement in Central
Bihar,” Economic & Political Weekly,
Vol 40, No 15, pp 1536–49.
Chandra, Kanchan (2004): Why Ethnic Parties
Succeed: Patronage and Ethnic Headcounts in India, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Fraser, Nancy (1998): “Social
Justice in the Age of Identity Politics: Redistribution, Recognition,
Participation,” WZB Discussion Paper No FS I 98–108.
Hasan, Zoya (2001): “Transfer of Power?
Politics of Mass Mobilisation in UP,” Economic & Political Weekly, Vol 36,
No 46–47, pp 4401–9.
Jaffrelot, Christophe (2003):
India’s Silent Revolution: The Rise of the Lower Castes in North India, Orient
Blackswan.
Jeffrey, Craig, Patricia Jeffery,
and Roger Jeffery (2008): “Dalit Revolution? New Politicians in Uttar Pradesh,
India,” The Journal of Asian Studies, Vol 67, No 4, pp 1365–96.
Kohli, Atul (2001): Introduction,
The Success of India’s Democracy,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Varshney, Ashutosh (2000): “Is
India Becoming More Democratic?” The Journal of Asian Studies, Vol 59, No 1, pp 3–25.
Weiner, Myron (2001): “The Struggle for
Equality: Caste in Indian Politics,” The Success of India’s Democracy, Atul
Kohli (ed), Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.